Podchaser Logo
Home
How a DOJ Economist Approaches Antitrust in America

How a DOJ Economist Approaches Antitrust in America

Released Thursday, 23rd May 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
How a DOJ Economist Approaches Antitrust in America

How a DOJ Economist Approaches Antitrust in America

How a DOJ Economist Approaches Antitrust in America

How a DOJ Economist Approaches Antitrust in America

Thursday, 23rd May 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:03

Bloomberg Audio Studios, Podcasts,

0:06

Radio News.

0:19

Hello and welcome to another episode of

0:21

the Odd Thoughts Podcast. I'm Tracy Allaway.

0:24

And I'm Joe Wisenthal.

0:26

Joe, we've done a little bit at this point

0:28

on antitrust. I feel like, kind

0:30

of interestingly, the first time

0:32

it ever really came up substantively

0:36

for us was I think

0:38

it was like way back in twenty

0:40

twenty or maybe twenty twenty one, where

0:43

we were talking about the potential for antitrust

0:45

enforcement to bring down inflation.

0:47

I don't know if you remember that totally.

0:49

No, I do remember it. I think we were talking about it

0:51

actually in the context of shipping at

0:53

the time. Yeah, of course, the major source of inflationary

0:56

pressure was the stress on supply chains. But

0:58

then that brought away, I would say.

1:01

And then it's since you know people paying

1:03

attention to it more, which is that you

1:05

know how to bottlenecks emerge? How do

1:07

inflationary bottlenecks merge? One theory

1:09

one source of these inflationary

1:12

bottlenecks is parts of the economy

1:15

where there's not very good competition.

1:17

Yeah.

1:17

Absolutely. And the other interesting thing

1:19

that's been happening recently is it

1:21

feels like definitions of anti

1:24

trust and anti competitive

1:26

practices have been expanding, right.

1:28

You hear this term hipster antitrust

1:31

all the time, this idea that maybe

1:33

anti competitive behavior doesn't just materialize

1:36

in things like prices, but

1:38

also in things like labor practices.

1:40

Totally. I think the rise

1:43

of the huge tech giants has contributed

1:45

to this because you do have

1:47

this situation in which it

1:50

feels like there are entities.

1:52

Look, if you have like a gigantic steel

1:54

monopoly or whatever, how is that going

1:56

to manifest itself as being bad

1:59

for the economy, Probably by really high

2:01

steel prices, right. I think in some

2:03

of these other business models, you

2:05

sense that there is concern about

2:08

corporate power, corporate concentration,

2:11

extremely powerful companies, but it

2:13

doesn't necessarily manifest as higher

2:16

prices. In fact, it maybe lower prices, and it

2:18

may be or maybe there's something not priced

2:20

at all, like right, none of us pay Facebook

2:22

directly or whatever it is some of these big social media giants,

2:25

And so I think that has probably contributed to

2:27

some extent for like, how

2:29

do we address market power through

2:31

outside the lens strictly of consumer

2:34

prices?

2:34

Absolutely, And the other thing just going

2:36

back to shipping. It feels like anti trust is

2:38

also potentially getting more attention

2:41

in the context of supply chain resiliency.

2:43

Right, So, yes, you can have high prices

2:45

because of a monopoly that dominates

2:48

a particular industry, but you could also

2:50

have a situation where if something

2:52

happens, if there's a choke point on

2:54

that business, as we've seen a number of

2:56

times in recent years, that it

2:58

creates a vulnerable for the entire

3:01

economy. So all of this got me

3:03

thinking, you know, clearly there is

3:06

an impact from antitrust

3:08

on the overall shape

3:11

and functioning of the economy,

3:13

and you see that kind of burst into the

3:15

policy debate every once in a while. But

3:17

I really wanted to dive into how

3:19

do you start to judge the effects of corporate

3:21

concentration on the overall

3:24

economy? And I have the perfect

3:26

guest for you, Joe Great, We're going to be speaking

3:28

to someone whose day job is basically

3:31

exactly this. We're going to be speaking

3:33

with Joanna Marinesque. She is the principal

3:36

economist at the Department of Justice's

3:38

Antitrust Division, also a professor

3:40

at the University of Pennsylvania.

3:42

Joanna, thank you so much for coming on all thoughts.

3:45

Thank you so much for having me.

3:46

What does a principal economist

3:48

at the DOJ actually do walk us

3:51

through your sort of day to.

3:52

Day absolutely so you know, in

3:55

my day job, what we do is we investigate

3:57

different companies for potential violation

4:00

of the anti trust laws and so

4:02

you know all these competition issues that you

4:04

just talked about. And so as

4:06

an economist, what I do there is

4:09

I oversee the work of my whole

4:11

team of PhD economists where

4:13

they go and do data analysis

4:16

in order to uncover the effects

4:19

of anti competitive practices on all

4:21

sorts of outcomes like prices

4:23

and wages and the quality of products

4:26

and so on and so forth. And we use

4:29

both quantitative analysis as well as

4:31

interviews and documents that

4:33

we are able to get from the companies

4:35

like emails, to better understand

4:37

how competition works in that particular

4:40

case and whether there is

4:42

in fact a sign of anti competitive

4:44

behavior.

4:45

So we talked about in the intro the

4:47

sort of antitrust thinking, maybe widening

4:49

the aperture of where you would look to

4:52

find evidence of uncompetitive

4:54

behavior beyond perhaps just

4:56

consumer prices. What type of data

4:59

are you looking when you talk about your going shifting

5:01

through all this data to look for evident what

5:03

are the types of data that you might look

5:05

at and what might be I guess, the signatures

5:08

of a company or an industry in which

5:10

anti competitive actions are a

5:12

problem.

5:14

So there are two main types of data

5:16

that I would point to. The first one is

5:18

on market shares, so you look at

5:20

the share of the companies

5:23

in their market. So this could be

5:25

a labor market or a product market. So

5:28

you know, if a company has a high

5:30

share and merges with another company that also

5:32

has a high share, then that's likely to raise

5:34

anti competitive concerns

5:37

in the sense that prices or wages

5:40

might be affected in a bad

5:42

direction. So that's one way

5:44

that we look at things again, calculating

5:46

market shares, and so that's for

5:49

one approach to looking at potential

5:51

for anti competitive harm. And we

5:54

can also talk about dominant firms,

5:56

so firms that have monopoly

5:58

power. That's also one of ways to

6:00

measure it is through market shares. And

6:02

then the second way is looking at

6:06

what we called head to head competition, So how

6:08

much do firms directly compete with each other?

6:10

And this would be found in

6:13

things like they are called win loss data.

6:15

So when you look at sales data,

6:18

you're looking at what company you lost

6:20

your business too. And that would show if

6:22

you often lose business to another

6:24

company that now you're trying to merge with. Well,

6:27

once you're merging, there's no longer going

6:29

to be that competition, the intense

6:31

competition between the two. And so

6:33

that's the second like broad category

6:36

of data. And there's similar data for workers.

6:38

If you constantly lose your workers to your

6:41

competitor and now you're merging, that

6:43

competition is going to be lost.

6:45

Oh that's really interesting.

6:46

So something like that win loss

6:48

data, how would you actually access

6:50

that? Where does that come from?

6:52

So that comes directly from the company's

6:54

data. So we because

6:56

you know we're the Department of Justice, if you're under

6:59

investigation with the companies

7:01

must send us their data, not

7:04

any data, but of course the data that's needed for the

7:06

investigation that concerns the specific

7:09

concern we have with potential

7:11

adverse effects on competition. So

7:13

companies send us the data, whether

7:15

it's again on the product for labor

7:18

markets, it would be data from things

7:21

like an applicant tracking system where they

7:23

see where people are coming from. So

7:25

that can also allow us to know where they're

7:27

hiring employees from and therefore trace

7:30

back the competition for labor.

7:33

So that sort of data you would get

7:35

that once an investigation had

7:37

already been started. Talk to us about

7:40

identifying potential investigations

7:43

and what sort of information

7:45

and data you would be looking at there,

7:47

or maybe you're looking at something like the

7:49

overall impact on the labor

7:52

market or prices, which we've already discussed.

7:55

Right, So for mergers, that's

7:57

sort of the bread and butter. There is

8:00

requirement for companies to file

8:02

so called HSR forms for any

8:05

transaction that's above some threshold, and

8:07

so in those forms they give

8:09

us some basic information about

8:11

why they're seeking to merge, you know, what

8:14

markets this might affect, and so on

8:16

and so forth. And actually we now have new

8:19

proposed additional information

8:21

on labor so that it's easier to look

8:23

at potential labor market effects.

8:25

So based on that, there's an initial screening

8:28

to see if we think that there might be

8:30

potentially anti competitive effects from

8:32

the merger. Then you know, there's an

8:34

initial investigation phase and basically

8:37

it goes from step to step until

8:39

we are satisfied that it's likely not going

8:41

to substantially lessen competition or

8:44

it could end up in a lawsuit to

8:46

try to block the merger if after having

8:48

done a lot of analysis and data and interviews,

8:51

we conclude that there's a substantial

8:54

risk that the transaction, the merger, would

8:57

lessen competition.

8:58

Not necessarily a specific merger

9:00

or an example, but just what would be a

9:03

style type of something. You

9:05

know, imagine company widget company

9:07

A wants to merge with widget company

9:10

B. They fill out this hs

9:13

R form for you, what

9:15

might be an example of something

9:17

that shows up that crosses

9:19

some threshold and in fact, is there a threshold

9:22

like is there a level of X or Y

9:24

in which like the red flag goes off, or

9:26

is there some level of subjectivity walk

9:28

us through like looking at that data

9:31

when the data flashes some alarm to take

9:34

this is not a good deal.

9:36

So the main there are many, of

9:38

course considerations that'd be hard to go

9:40

through here, but one of the main things

9:42

is the market shares. Okay, so if

9:44

we have some evidence that

9:47

these companies are competing in some

9:49

market for some widgets, some specific

9:51

widgets, so that's a specific product market,

9:54

let's say, and if both of those companies

9:56

have a high enough market share, that

9:59

raises alarm and in the merger guidelines. So we have

10:01

guidelines where we tell everybody this is public.

10:03

You can go see them. They are brand new. We just

10:05

put them out twenty twenty three Merger Guidelines.

10:08

It tells you exactly what that threshold is.

10:10

So what must your share be for

10:13

us to conclude that there

10:15

is a risk that competition might

10:18

be hurt in this merger. And again, the

10:20

general principle is that the two

10:22

companies must have a

10:24

high enough share in the market. So basically the

10:26

market we call it concentrated, so there's

10:29

few companies, each one has a large

10:31

share. And further, we require that

10:33

after the merger, the share

10:36

of the two companies combined increases

10:38

enough that it threatens competition. So

10:41

that's really a key screening

10:43

tool that we use, and

10:46

that's going to play an important role, you

10:48

know, as we go on with the investigation,

10:51

and why are shared is important. They

10:53

are important as an indicator of

10:56

how anti competitive effects could

10:58

happen. And this could be either

11:00

through a reduction in what we call

11:02

again competition direct competition for

11:05

customers or for workers,

11:07

or it could also be through potentially

11:10

an increased risk of collision that

11:13

whether explicit or implicit.

11:15

The few actors they are in the market, and

11:17

the easier it is for them to agree,

11:21

let's say to you know, increased

11:23

prices a little bit or let's say keep

11:25

wages down a little bit more, something

11:27

like that.

11:43

What happens in a non competitive

11:45

economy? Walk us through the sort of side

11:47

effects of having high corporate

11:50

concentration.

11:51

Yeah, so there are many adverse

11:54

effects, but broadly, some of these effects

11:56

are higher prices,

11:59

lower wages is less innovation,

12:02

so you know, just broadly, and lower

12:04

product quality, lower wage quality. So,

12:07

for example, for the labor market, if

12:09

we just take that as an example, because

12:11

of a lack of competition, so if you're

12:13

an employee and you don't have anywhere

12:15

else to go, that would be a good firm that you would

12:18

like. Similarly, just as well as your current

12:20

employer. That means that the employer

12:22

can pay you less because where are you going to go?

12:24

And so you know, I have a paper,

12:26

for example, and others have written related

12:29

academic papers, and you can show

12:31

that if we got rid

12:33

of this lack of competition, wages may

12:36

increase by as much as twenty percent

12:38

on average. You know, in the extreme case that

12:40

we could, you know, without all issues

12:42

with competition in the labor market. Now, if

12:44

you look at the product market, so

12:47

you know there's a lack of competition in various

12:49

markets for various widgets. Not

12:51

only that will increase prices,

12:54

reduce quality, and reduce consumer

12:56

choice, reduce innovation, but interestingly,

12:59

that will also have an adverse effect

13:01

on workers, which is an indirect

13:03

effect because when you have a monopoly, a

13:06

monopoly makes less stuff. They

13:08

produce less widgets,

13:10

fewer widgets, and in order to

13:12

produce fuel widgets, well, that also means

13:15

fuel widgets means you need fewer workers

13:17

to produce the wigets. So there's a

13:19

less demand for labor, less demand

13:22

for workers. So therefore that reduces employment

13:24

opportunities. And there's really cool new

13:26

academic work that's still work in progress

13:29

by Tanya Babina and co authors suggesting

13:31

that when the anti trust authorities

13:34

go in and enforce the anti trust law and

13:36

stimulate competition the product

13:38

market, you see an increase in employment

13:41

as business flourishes, and

13:44

they also need more workers to produce

13:46

whatever it is that they're producing.

13:48

One of the arguments that you know, one

13:51

thing that can theoretically happen. I don't

13:53

know if it happens in practice. But one thing

13:55

that can theoretically happen is

13:57

that two companies can combine and

14:00

become more efficient, and that means

14:02

that they have economies of scale, and maybe they can

14:04

lower prices. Maybe

14:06

that scale brings consumer

14:08

benefits with the lower prices, et cetera. From

14:11

an economist perspective, I'm

14:13

sure there are many instances where companies

14:15

say that that's what will happen, and

14:17

it seems at least possible. Is

14:20

it possible in your view that concentration

14:22

can lead to better consumer outcomes,

14:24

either a from a price

14:26

perspective or from a here's a very powerful

14:29

company that then becomes a wage ceter or

14:31

you just sort of would you be per se skeptical

14:34

of those claims.

14:35

So, you know, in general, as

14:37

with every claim where you know the

14:39

companies have an interest in making that claim,

14:42

we need to examine it, you

14:44

know, with fairness and with evidence. And

14:46

you know, if you look at the merger Guidelands, there's a whole

14:49

section on efficiencies, recognizing

14:51

that that's a possibility, but we also

14:53

ask that those efficiencies, if claimed,

14:56

be well documented, you

14:58

know, clearly articulated, verified by outside

15:01

experts, so that we can start to

15:03

potentially consider them, and we find

15:05

that oftentimes that's just not the case.

15:08

And so you know, again it's all

15:10

a fact based investigation and you have to

15:12

look at it. But that's certainly something

15:14

that we consider in the holistic assessment

15:17

of what's going to happen. Since it's

15:19

a predictive exercise, we have to assess

15:21

the risk. We take that into account

15:23

as one element.

15:25

Just to press you on this part

15:27

further, as an economist

15:29

coming to the table and there are other people, there are

15:32

lawyers or others at the table, what

15:34

are some of the tools in your arsenal

15:36

that you might use, or tools in your toolbox

15:39

per se, that you might use to

15:41

make such a prediction to evaluate

15:43

claims of economies of scale

15:45

and such things.

15:47

So what we essentially,

15:49

it's important to note that it's

15:51

not up to us the Department of Justice,

15:54

to make that point. It's rather that

15:56

the companies must be able

15:58

to prove with some evidence

16:01

that these efficiencies are likely to

16:03

result and be not only that there

16:05

are efficiency at all, which might

16:07

well be the case, but that they are sufficiently

16:10

substantial that they will negate

16:12

the anti competitive effects that we fear,

16:15

and so and of course, the specifics

16:17

against specific But what's really

16:19

important is not just to show that there

16:21

are some efficiencies, but

16:24

that they are again substantive

16:26

enough that the initial concern

16:29

that we had for all the adverse anti competitive

16:31

effects is likely not to materialize

16:34

because you know, those efficiencies

16:36

make the market so much more competitive. But

16:39

again the burden of proof in terms of who

16:41

must show that that's the economists

16:43

of the other side.

16:45

So one of the more interesting cases

16:48

that the DOJ took on over

16:50

the past because it was a few

16:53

years since it started, but the

16:56

Penguins acquisition of Simon

16:58

and Schuster, and part of this

17:00

is media naval gazing because

17:02

it involves the publishing industry, and

17:05

if you read some of the complaints and the other

17:07

documents around this, there is just oodles

17:09

and oodles of information on

17:12

like the actual numbers behind publishing

17:15

and how they come up with things like author

17:17

advances, how much they spend on marketing.

17:20

Stuff like that.

17:21

But walk us through the economic lessons

17:24

of a case like that, because

17:26

there seem to have been some trade

17:29

offs in that particular action.

17:31

So you know, I was really excited to see that

17:33

case. This was ongoing when I

17:35

arrived in my job at the division and

17:38

just to table sat a little bit. That

17:40

case was a case where Penguin

17:43

Random House was seeking to merge

17:45

with another big publisher, Simon and Schuster,

17:47

and we always first look at competition

17:50

in this industry, and in this case were interesting

17:52

competition for authors. So

17:55

you know this big publisher publishing

17:57

houses, they are trying to buy the rights

17:59

to author's books, and

18:01

so for big name authors,

18:04

they're on that many publishing houses.

18:06

In fact, there are only five so called big

18:09

five publishing companies that

18:11

vuy typically for books

18:13

by famous authors. And so we

18:16

focus specifically on what we

18:18

called anticipated top selling books,

18:20

which were books that would get an advance

18:22

of two hundred and fifty thousand dollars or

18:24

more. So we're talking here about you

18:26

know, likely big selling books.

18:29

And so in that market again

18:31

for those big big books, Penguin

18:33

Random House had the market share

18:35

there. We got market share, remember we talked about that

18:38

before, of thirty seven percent and

18:40

Simon and Schuster twelve percent, and

18:42

so you can see that together after

18:45

the merger, if it had happened, they would essentially

18:47

have half of that

18:49

market. And so that's like a really

18:51

significant change in

18:54

market shares. That would give these

18:56

publishing houses significant market power. And

18:58

what's the market power here, it's

19:00

the market power over

19:03

authors. When authors are shopping

19:05

around the manuscript to find a publisher

19:07

that they like that gives them good conditions.

19:10

Again, that's what they do. They shop around and they make

19:12

competition play who's giving me the best

19:14

terms? And once these

19:17

publishing houses would have merged, that

19:19

would remove an option for

19:22

the authors to get a better

19:24

deal for their books. And so therefore we

19:26

predicted that they would get

19:28

lower advances, and

19:31

that would therefore damage competition in

19:33

that market for the author's work. And this

19:35

is the judge agreed with us.

19:37

And so this is the first merger that was

19:40

blocked primarily on a theory

19:42

of labor market

19:44

power, where those publishing houses

19:47

would exercise power

19:50

over the labor of the authors

19:52

in this specific case, is.

19:54

There a you know you mentioned okay,

19:56

a company with thirty seven percent market

19:58

share want to merge with twelve percent market

20:01

share almost fifty percent? Is

20:03

there a number in which this is

20:05

too much? Does it vary by industry? Like,

20:07

where is this threshold exist such

20:10

that you could say, okay, this is an

20:12

okay level of market power or this is

20:14

too much.

20:15

Right, So that's in the merger

20:18

guidelines. We have a famous

20:20

you know, this is nerdy nerdy, but we have an

20:22

index try The HHI is

20:24

actually the Herd fineral Hershman index

20:26

that essentially boils down to market

20:29

shares. So if the market

20:31

shares in the market are generally high

20:33

enough, you're going to have a market that's already

20:35

we call it highly concentrated. And then

20:38

from there, if the merger is going to increase

20:40

it sufficiently in this concentration, making

20:43

the market even more concentrated

20:45

with fewer players, then

20:47

we think that it, you know, presumptively,

20:49

is going to cause an anti competitive effect.

20:52

And this, you know, this is this is

20:54

something that you can calculate, and the thresholds

20:57

are there in the merger guidelines.

20:58

Wait, so, speaking of calculations

21:01

and nerding out, when it comes

21:03

time to try to predict

21:05

the effect of this type of

21:07

consolidation on advances

21:09

for authors and their proposed books,

21:12

presumably you go about actually modeling

21:15

that in one way or another. How

21:17

do you do something like that for publishing,

21:19

which is kind of a notoriously opaque

21:22

industry in many ways.

21:24

That's right, So, you know, as I was

21:26

saying, it's always very fact specific,

21:29

and actually one of the coolest things that

21:31

I've learned by being at the division is

21:33

just the very many different details

21:35

of each industry that you know, as an academic,

21:37

you don't access this level

21:40

of detail, you know, or manage as

21:42

a journalist. If you could get all

21:44

the you know, various emails and

21:46

all these documents about what's really going on,

21:49

it's really juicy. So but

21:51

essentially here in this case, there's

21:54

a process of bargaining and shopping around

21:57

the manuscripts, and there's various ways

21:59

how this could happen, but typically it's

22:01

some sort of auction like format,

22:04

and so therefore our expert in

22:07

this case we work with an

22:09

outside economic expert who does

22:11

some of the analysis, and so he modeled

22:14

an auction style situation

22:16

where those firms, now instead

22:18

of each bidding independently, would

22:21

be together and calculated.

22:23

You know, the fact that it would

22:25

likely result in a significant decrease

22:28

in what the authors were going to be able to get

22:31

for their books.

22:33

You know, one thing in staying with the books

22:35

example, but maybe it's not the best example.

22:38

Another element of these fights

22:40

is fights over the definition of

22:42

what constitutes a market, and maybe

22:44

in books, it's kind of clear. We're

22:47

talking about books and there's five big publishers,

22:49

and so, okay, there's an advance

22:51

and everything. But one

22:54

could theoretically make the argument that the

22:56

market is more than just five book

22:58

publishers. And we live in an age of

23:00

social media and writers maybe

23:03

not doing a book, maybe doing a deal with

23:05

Netflix and turning it into

23:07

a documentary or other

23:09

vehicles that are not precisely

23:11

booked, but that may be a vehicle

23:14

for an author or researcher or

23:16

writer to get there out. Where does

23:18

the fight over what constitutes

23:21

the market itself occur or when does

23:23

that occur?

23:24

Well, you're really pointing the you know,

23:26

putting your finger here. You're putting your finger

23:28

on a fundamental question in those

23:30

anti trust cases, which is what's the

23:32

market. And importantly it's it's

23:35

not like there is the market, it's we

23:37

have to show a relevant market based

23:39

on how competition works. And so here

23:43

we define the market as this anticipated

23:46

stop selling books two hundred and fifty k

23:49

or more. But again you could say, well, they

23:51

could self published on published on Amazon,

23:53

right, and so that's where the

23:56

critical question becomes, Yes, but is

23:58

this other way of publishing a

24:00

reasonable substitute from the point

24:02

of view of those authors. That's really

24:05

a critical question that we go

24:07

about asking and for that we use

24:09

a tool, again very nerd. It's

24:11

called the hypothetical monopsonist test.

24:14

And so what this asks is whether a

24:16

hypothetical publishing

24:18

house that would become a monopsist,

24:20

meaning that they would be the only publishing house, not

24:23

five Big five, the only one,

24:25

would they be able to impose

24:28

a small but significant reduction

24:30

in the advances that are paid to

24:33

these authors. And if we find that

24:35

that would likely happen, that means

24:38

that the market is well defined. And basically

24:40

what that boils down to is authors

24:42

just don't have other viable

24:44

options, other equivalent options

24:47

outside of this market.

24:50

So you mentioned looking at various

24:52

industries, and I can only imagine

24:55

how interesting that must be with the amount

24:57

of data, first person data

24:59

that you that you get to see.

25:02

But one thing I was wondering is, you

25:04

know, you jump from sort of industry to industry.

25:06

So I think in recent times you've looked

25:08

at publishing, which we just discussed,

25:10

You've looked at nursing,

25:13

You've looked at things like poultry processing,

25:16

and also video games, can

25:18

you maybe single out one

25:20

of those that was most interesting to you

25:23

or one where you've learned something

25:25

new about how that particular industry

25:27

worked.

25:28

For sure, I think one of the coolest

25:31

cases I've gotten to work on. And

25:33

my kids got super excited about this because

25:35

they played a lot of video games. Concerned

25:38

video game tournament, the Overwatch

25:40

League, So this is organized by Activision

25:43

Blizzard, so that was like

25:45

a really cool case. And

25:47

what happened there is that it's really

25:50

interesting. So they have professional video

25:52

game players who get paid to

25:55

play video games. I'm sure that's the dream

25:57

for some people. And

26:00

and so what was happening there is that they had

26:02

a soft cap on workers' salaries.

26:04

So it was the case that each team

26:07

could not pay more than a

26:09

certain amount or else the additional

26:12

pay above that amount would get taxed

26:14

away. And so that meant that

26:16

the teams had a strong incentive to keep

26:18

the tool pay to the whole team,

26:21

you know, not go above the threshold. And

26:23

so what we said therefore is that this

26:25

is reducing competition for workers.

26:28

Here. The workers are video game players,

26:30

professionals, they won't be able to

26:32

get paid as much as they would get

26:34

paid without this restriction right, because

26:36

again the teams are strongly

26:39

disincentivized from increasing the wages

26:42

above this cap. And what's really

26:44

interesting is that there are similar

26:46

rules in other leagues like the

26:48

NBA and the NFL, but those rules

26:51

are collectively bargained and

26:53

whereas in video games there's no

26:55

unionization, and so these

26:57

rules were imposed without the workers,

27:00

in this case, the professional video game players

27:02

being able to have a say in

27:05

the rules. And so to me, that case

27:07

is really interesting not only for the video

27:09

game context, but also for the

27:11

interesting consideration of what happens

27:14

with collective bargaining or here the absence

27:16

thereof and therefore our prediction

27:18

that those rules you know, are imposed

27:21

on workers without their consent and are

27:23

going to significantly diminish their

27:25

pay.

27:26

Major League Baseball actually has an

27:28

official legal exemption the anti

27:30

trust law.

27:31

Yes, and that's really important because historically

27:35

one of the ways that the anti trust laws could

27:37

be used is to bust the unions because the

27:39

you know, the workers agree with each

27:41

other. Normally they should compete, but they agree.

27:44

And so it was decided from a policy

27:46

perspective that there would be an exemption for

27:49

union bargain bargaining that

27:51

you know, the the unions cannot be sued

27:54

by the Anti Trust Division for doing collective

27:57

bargaining, and so that's why it's different.

28:00

If there is a union is one thing. If there

28:02

is no union, it's a different thing. And so

28:04

in this case of the Overwatch

28:06

League, you know, the company agreed

28:08

not to do this again, you know, to limit

28:10

the workers' pay because again there

28:13

was no agreement with the worker through

28:15

bargaining, but instead it was just imposed

28:17

on workers against their will and would

28:20

likely reduce wages that the

28:22

workers are being paid.

28:23

This might be a very theoretical question, but we've

28:25

obviously been talking about the impact

28:28

of concentration on prices

28:31

and labor. Are there other effects

28:33

where you could see a sort of

28:36

anti trust argument playing

28:38

out, like other consequences on the

28:40

economy that might be worth looking at

28:43

for sure.

28:44

I think, you know, another aspect

28:46

that we haven't touched upon as much but

28:48

is innovation. And you know, innovation

28:51

is really important and one of

28:53

the you know, in order to create new jobs

28:55

and new businesses. So you know, we really

28:58

need innovation to grow, and

29:00

that innovation can be really thwarted

29:03

by anti competitive behavior

29:06

by you know, big, big actors

29:08

who monopolize markets. And

29:10

so you know, for example, we have

29:13

filed a lawsuit against Apple

29:16

as an example, and you know, one

29:18

of the arguments there is that Apple

29:21

is preventing its users

29:23

from switching to alternative

29:25

smartphones and one of

29:27

the ill effects of that is

29:30

a reduction in innovation. So essentially, the

29:32

big picture vision

29:34

here I just want to make clear

29:36

is that the anti competitive

29:38

behavior decreases innovation.

29:41

We're not saying that the company isn't innovating

29:43

at all. It's more like if there was more competition,

29:46

they'd be innovating more. So what does this mean

29:48

intuitively, is if you're able to

29:50

hold your audience captive as a company,

29:52

you know, you're it's very hard for the customer

29:54

to move away from your product. You just

29:56

don't have the same incentive to make

29:59

your product re good for the customer

30:01

in order to keep them. Whereas if there's a lot of competition,

30:04

well there's always a risk of losing the customer,

30:07

And now you're really incentivized to work

30:09

hard to innovate so that the customer

30:11

wants to stay with you rather than switching to

30:13

somebody else.

30:30

Since you mentioned tech and Apple

30:32

and innovation, there's a line

30:35

of thinking in economics, which is that

30:37

maybe the way we do official

30:40

economic statistics at the moment isn't

30:43

necessarily the best at capturing

30:45

the new economy, for lack of a better word,

30:48

like maybe productivity.

30:50

It's harder to measure productivity

30:52

improvements in something like a video

30:54

game or a phone, or I don't know, a

30:56

refrigerator that now comes with a

30:58

bluetooth speaker or whatever. I'm

31:01

curious if the same dynamic kind

31:03

of exists in anti trust

31:05

laws and enforcement. Does it feel

31:08

to you like the current tools

31:10

at your disposal are adequate

31:13

to capture maybe some of the new

31:15

anti trust challenges being thrown

31:17

up by a more modern economy.

31:20

Right, So, I think, you know, that's precisely

31:22

why we created the or you know,

31:24

we worked together with the FTC to

31:27

put out the twenty twenty three

31:29

merger guidelines. You know, we have taken

31:32

to heart all of those new technological

31:35

developments and you know, new ways

31:37

of looking at old problems,

31:39

and so, for example, you know, I mentioned

31:42

innovation as being one important consideration,

31:45

and in the merger guidelines, for example,

31:47

we pay special attention to let's

31:50

say, acquisition of nascent competitors

31:52

where a dominant player might be

31:54

buying a smaller company that is

31:56

very promising and might come to eat their lunch,

31:59

and so it really pay attention to that. And

32:01

also with respect to labor,

32:03

it's not all about wages, but we're also

32:05

looking at things like working conditions.

32:07

You know, how flexible the work is, maybe

32:10

special hybrid arrangements,

32:12

right, talking about technology that workers

32:14

might really enjoy. If there's less competition

32:17

for workers, there's less incentive for firms

32:19

to come up with creative ideas of organizing

32:22

work in ways that you know

32:24

will make people happy and productive

32:27

at work. So I think, you know, the new merger

32:29

guidelines have really learned

32:31

from recent developments in technology

32:33

and you know, in the economics literature to

32:35

look at a broader area

32:38

of potential effects

32:40

from anti competitive behavior that isn't just

32:43

limited to prices, which is usually the bread

32:45

and but of course we look at prices, but

32:47

there's all these other aspects like you

32:49

know, as I said, wages, but also innovation

32:52

and the quality of jobs.

32:54

When it comes to innovation, and

32:56

you brought up the Apple case, so on the one

32:58

hand, you could say it's anti competitive from

33:00

an innovation standpoint because

33:03

the frictions that they make make it hard for

33:05

a user or a consumer to move

33:08

from one type of smartphone to another. On

33:10

the other hand, one could argue

33:12

that actually it's good for innovation because

33:15

if you pool a ton of users

33:17

onto a single platform, then someone

33:19

can build a product and have this huge,

33:22

a wide swath of people

33:24

that they can target, and that opens up

33:27

anything. You mentioned big companies

33:29

buying up small companies. Maybe

33:31

that is anti competitive in one sense. But on the

33:33

other hand, if small companies view

33:35

an exit to a large company as

33:37

a likely outcome and the alternative of

33:40

an IPO, then maybe that funds

33:43

the investment in more companies in the first

33:45

place. So I guess what I'm asking is, how do you

33:47

actually measure or is there a way

33:49

to measure innovation or

33:51

what are the tools you use to actually

33:54

measure the effect of some corporate

33:56

behavior of some deal on the

33:58

amount of innovation, which seems like kind of

34:00

a hard thing to strictly quantified.

34:02

It's very hard to quantify directly,

34:05

and so that's why we are relying

34:07

on again industry specific documents.

34:10

So, I mean, what you have to realize is, like

34:12

we're talking here in the abstract, but in the concrete

34:15

case, we have like

34:17

like information.

34:19

So what are the things that come up in the course

34:22

of a case that you're like, Okay, this is useful

34:24

data or this is signal that can tell

34:27

us something about the net

34:29

effect on innovation. That's something in the tech space

34:31

would have.

34:32

So like, for example, if we are

34:35

looking at the concrete case and we are

34:37

looking at let's say a dominant

34:39

company and its practices, we

34:42

often see evidence on

34:44

smaller competitors that let's

34:46

say there might be an anecdote where

34:48

you know, we know that they brought a new product

34:51

and the product in question was very

34:53

popular, but let's say you

34:55

know, the dominant firm

34:58

made sure that the product cannot take off

35:00

by imposing all sorts of restrictions.

35:02

Because you know, there's all sorts of ways. It's very

35:05

industry specific, but there are ways,

35:07

and that's what we're going after. It's so called exclusionary

35:09

practices. There are ways for the dominant

35:12

companies to make sure that that new, upstart,

35:15

cool product, you know, finds

35:17

it hard to find a market and so

35:20

and so that's what we really want to have

35:22

our eyes wide open toward, is

35:25

to be able to detect

35:27

those kinds of behaviors and you

35:29

know, if possible, curb it

35:31

right. And again, extreme behavior would be to literally

35:34

buy up that company that has the cool new product,

35:36

you know, and maybe potentially do

35:38

a killer acquisition, you know, just

35:41

kill that product so that it never it never comes

35:43

to comes to market. So there's all sorts of things

35:45

that companies can do, and

35:47

we have to be very vigilant

35:50

about all these strategies. And companies often

35:52

say, oh, but we are so great, we so

35:54

innovative, and that's really missing

35:56

the point because nobody said they're not innovative

35:59

the big player. It's more about

36:01

how much innovation is lost through

36:04

their anti compantive behavior. The point is we could have

36:06

even better stuff, yea, even better

36:08

working conditions, even more

36:10

innovation if there was more competition.

36:12

So I just have one more question, and I've asked

36:15

this before on conversation

36:17

about anti trust, but I'm curious to get your perspective

36:19

within the context of you know, we're

36:22

this administration is

36:24

undertaking a number of policy

36:27

measures. People call it industrial policy,

36:29

for example, and in some case it

36:31

involves just giving one money, one

36:33

company money, or a few companies money. And

36:36

in theory that you know, that's

36:38

a major advantage to them, let's say a competitor

36:41

might not have. And so we're sort

36:43

of at a time in which you know, we are

36:45

sort of to some extent picking winners

36:47

or picking candidates

36:49

who could be winners depending on how they execute.

36:52

Can you talk a little bit, maybe philosophically or

36:54

from your perspective, how you see

36:57

anti trust enforcement fitting

36:59

in with the sort of broader, broader

37:02

policy landscape in which

37:04

the administration is not just sort of letting

37:06

the invisible hand to determine who's

37:08

going to win and who's going to build on, but it's actually

37:11

shaping and guiding corporate behavior in

37:13

multiple industries.

37:16

HM. So I think what I can best say

37:18

about this is that we work,

37:20

you know, to foster competition

37:23

given other you know, existing

37:25

rules and constraints. So we take the other

37:28

stuff as given, and you

37:30

know, if there's rules out there, there's rules

37:32

we don't. You know, we're not here to change

37:34

legislation or anything like that, and we're looking

37:37

at, hey, is there a competition

37:39

problem within the existing

37:41

rules, and we're going after

37:43

that. So I think it's like just you

37:45

know, each tool in its own

37:48

sort of domain of application. There's

37:50

many policy goals and you know, I don't want

37:52

to comment about other policies outside

37:55

us. What we do is given

37:58

again, what every other I know. Actually

38:00

a good example of this in labor again is

38:02

the union topic. Right,

38:04

So unions got an exception.

38:07

We take that as a given. So we're not going to go

38:10

after unions. You know, they they

38:12

by legislation, and that's really important in

38:14

democracy. If the legislature

38:16

decided to make the law a certain way,

38:19

that's how it is, and we respect that. And

38:21

then we're asking, given that, you

38:24

know, what other competition is there, and how

38:26

might workers and consumers

38:28

gain if we intervene

38:31

in order to foster more competition. That

38:33

would lead to again lower prices, more

38:35

innovation, higher wages, better quality

38:37

jobs.

38:38

So just on this note, Joe kind of

38:40

reminded me. But going back to the supply

38:43

chain issue and the experience of the pandemic,

38:45

I mean, I think there is a realization that

38:48

concentration can have negative consequences

38:51

in terms of overall resiliency

38:53

of the system. So if you have one supplier

38:56

of something that is strategically important

38:58

and then there I don't know, a COVID

39:01

outbreak in their factory or something like that,

39:03

then you could have the entire supply of that good

39:06

curtailed basically. And the other

39:08

thing that seems to have happened recently is there's

39:10

more recognition of the cascade

39:12

effects in the economy. So economists

39:15

like Isabella Weber have been working

39:17

on this idea of systemically important

39:19

sources of inflation or

39:22

where you could get higher prices in one

39:24

particular good that's a building block

39:26

of a number of other things, and then that sort

39:28

of flows through the entire economy.

39:31

So I'm curious as someone who does this at

39:34

the DOJ. This is your job, your day

39:36

to day, is supply

39:38

chain resiliency or

39:41

kind of on your radar at all? Is

39:43

that something that you would be looking at as well.

39:46

I mean, I think one way that

39:48

this intersects with our bread and butter

39:50

concerns is through entry.

39:53

So you know, we're always looking

39:55

at in order to predict whether,

39:58

let's say a merger is going to

40:00

significantly affect competition

40:02

in a negative way. So these two companies

40:05

are merging, and is that going to increase

40:07

prices, that going to reduce wages? One

40:09

key question is once they merge,

40:12

let's say they're trying to do something bad like

40:14

increased prices. Are they going

40:16

to be able to do so? And one way

40:18

that they would be limited in that is

40:21

by entry from other companies.

40:23

If we strongly believe that,

40:26

you know, this is a market that's

40:28

very dynamic and there's a lot of entry,

40:30

or on the opposite, it's a market that's not all

40:33

dynamic. There hasn't been a new company that

40:35

entered for the past twenty years. That

40:37

factors into our reasoning.

40:39

And I think this entry is

40:41

related to some extent to this concern

40:44

about resiliency, because you would think that

40:46

an industry where it's very

40:49

easy to enter, you know, it's very flexible,

40:52

you would have also less

40:54

of that other concern around resiliency

40:57

versus and this is resiliency to monopoly,

40:59

but it could potentially be residency to other

41:02

things. So again, I think that entry

41:04

consideration is really important to

41:06

look at the specifics of the industry

41:09

in terms of economies of scale or other barriers

41:11

to entry that could occur, be

41:14

there or not be there, And again it really

41:16

depends on the specifics of the industry.

41:18

All right, Johanna Marinescue from the

41:20

DOJ, thank you so much for coming on our

41:22

thoughts. That was absolutely fascinating.

41:25

Thank you so much.

41:26

Yeah, thank you so much.

41:27

That was great, Joe.

41:41

I'm so glad we did that episode because I remember,

41:43

I think maybe both with Lena Khan from

41:46

the FTC and then Jonathan Kanter from The DOJ,

41:48

both of which we have had on the podcast.

41:50

At this point, I think we were asking

41:53

them questions about their research process

41:55

and identifying, you know, potential

41:57

targets for lawsuits and things like

41:59

that. It was really interesting to hear

42:02

the economists perspective on

42:04

this totally.

42:05

I like hearing about like all the different tools

42:08

and forms and stuff like that, right, because

42:10

one of the things that came up in some of our previous

42:13

conversations is like, well some of it's like

42:15

anecdotal, right, or some of it you hear things

42:17

and you say, oh, you read something in the paper and you're

42:19

like, hmm, something seems kind of weird here,

42:22

or people are complaining. But then hearing about

42:24

like specific tools, the type

42:26

of data that gets collected. What was

42:28

it the wind loss data?

42:30

Yeah, and also that one form I

42:32

can't remember.

42:34

Yeah, I have it up on my computer

42:37

right now, the HSR, the

42:39

pre merger notification form that you have

42:41

to fill out and that the onus is on

42:43

the companies to sort of demonstrate

42:46

preemptively that the merger is not going

42:48

to worsen the competitive situation.

42:51

I like hearing as you say about like all these

42:53

different now, all of these different

42:55

tactics and techniques and tools to actually

42:57

how these things get evaluated.

42:59

Yeah, and Yoanna is right that I would

43:01

love to as a journalist, I would love to see

43:03

that kind of.

43:04

I wish, you know what, I wish we could subpoena up here. I

43:06

think journalist should have subpoena power over our

43:08

corporate data. I think that would only be fair.

43:10

I guess we do have freedom of information requests,

43:13

but it's not quite the same companies. The

43:15

other thing I was thinking about, you know, I

43:17

know you keep asking this question to various

43:20

antitrust people about, you

43:22

know, the the active industrial

43:25

policy of the Biden administration versus

43:27

questions over competition and

43:29

things like that, and I think, you know, there is

43:32

a tension there that I think is probably

43:34

as yet unresolved.

43:36

Yeah.

43:36

I think so too.

43:37

I mean it's interesting or maybe

43:39

you know, one way to view it, like there

43:42

is this tension. The other argument I

43:44

think one could make is the

43:46

fact that the US is to some extent, picking

43:48

winners even further emphasizes

43:51

the need to enforce anti

43:53

trust and to so that you

43:56

know, because once you've been selected as a winner, a

43:58

candidate winner, so they're actually still

44:00

competing rather than basically

44:02

rent seeking. So maybe

44:05

they go hand in glove more than I

44:07

appreciate.

44:08

Absolutely. Shall we leave it there.

44:09

Let's leave it there.

44:10

This has been another episode of the Oudlots

44:12

podcast. I'm Tracy Alloway. You can follow

44:15

me at Tracy.

44:15

Alloway and I'm Joe Wisenthal. You can follow

44:18

me at the Stalwart. Follow our guest Joanna Maronescu.

44:20

She's at m Joanna. Follow

44:22

our producers Kerman Rodriguez at Kerman

44:25

Erman, dash Ol Bennett a Dashbot, and Kelbrooks

44:27

at Kelbrooks. Thank you to our producer Moses

44:30

ONEm. For more odd Logs content, go to

44:32

Bloomberg dot com slash odd Lots, where you have

44:34

transcripts of blog and weekly newsletter

44:36

comes out every Friday, and you can chat

44:38

about all of these topics twenty four to seven in

44:40

our discord discord do gg

44:43

slash odlines.

44:44

And if you enjoy odd Lots, if you like

44:46

it when we do these anti trust episodes.

44:48

Then please leave us a positive review

44:50

on your favorite podcast platform. And

44:52

remember, if you are a Bloomberg subscriber,

44:55

you can listen to all of our episodes absolutely

44:57

ad free. All you need to do is can

45:00

next your Bloomberg account with Apple

45:02

Podcasts. To do that, find

45:04

the Bloomberg channel on Apple Podcasts

45:06

and follow the instructions there. Thanks

45:08

for listening.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features