Podchaser Logo
Home
Can you put a price on nature?

Can you put a price on nature?

Released Wednesday, 19th June 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
Can you put a price on nature?

Can you put a price on nature?

Can you put a price on nature?

Can you put a price on nature?

Wednesday, 19th June 2024
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:00

Get 3% daily cash back when

0:03

you use Apple Card to buy a new

0:05

iPhone 15 or pair of AirPods at Apple.

0:07

You can choose to grow it at 4.40%

0:11

annual percentage yield APY when you

0:13

open a savings account through Apple

0:15

Card. Apply for Apple Card in

0:18

the Wallet app on iPhone. Subject

0:20

to credit approval, savings is available to

0:22

Apple Card owners subject to eligibility, savings

0:25

in Apple Card by Goldman Sachs

0:27

Bank USA, Salt Lake City branch,

0:29

member FDIC, terms and more at

0:31

applecard.com. How

0:42

much is a wild bat worth?

0:44

Bats are good, bats are friendly, bats eat

0:47

pests. But can we actually put

0:49

a dollar number on that goodness and

0:51

friendliness and pest eating? This

0:54

is a question that Amy Ando started asking herself

0:56

a few years ago at a conference. Because

0:59

there were some people there telling her about

1:01

something called White Nose Syndrome. The

1:05

fungus grows on the faces of bats while

1:07

they're hibernating. It's called White Nose Syndrome because

1:09

they end up with fuzzy white stuff on their noses. It

1:12

seems to irritate the bats, upsetting

1:14

their natural hibernation rhythms. This

1:16

is highly fatal to bats and

1:18

has been decimating bat populations. We

1:21

have seen populations of bats in

1:23

eastern colonies decline, in some

1:25

cases, to 100%. It

1:28

is a wildlife wipeout. Literally

1:30

millions and millions of bats in the

1:33

last two decades have died. Now,

1:36

there are potentially some solutions here, like

1:38

ways to keep bats from getting this

1:40

fungal infection and dying. But

1:42

those interventions are expensive. Stuff

1:45

like monitoring caves or protecting

1:47

bat habitats. People trudging

1:49

through bat caves full of

1:51

guano. Even developing vaccines.

1:54

You wouldn't want to do this unless it was

1:56

a very important thing to do. These are real

1:58

costs, both dollars. values

2:00

and, you know, human labor.

2:03

So, is it worth

2:05

doing? This,

2:09

of course, is a really hard question to

2:11

answer. But it's exactly

2:13

the kind of question that Amy Ando

2:15

answers for a living, because she's an

2:17

environmental economist. A lot of

2:19

people think that those two words are

2:21

opposites because economic activity is often the

2:23

thing that damages the environment. But

2:26

the way she sees it, using economics

2:28

to study the environment is actually key to

2:30

protecting it. Like, if we want to safeguard

2:32

the natural world... We need to

2:34

be able to quantify the benefits that

2:36

we get out of it. We can't just wave our

2:38

hands and say, oh, well, nature.

2:42

This is Unexplainable, I'm Benji Jones, and

2:44

today on the show, what

2:46

is a bat worth? I'm

2:50

here to talk about the economy. What, like

2:52

it's hard? You may be wondering, who got

2:54

all this money? Nobody knows. The

2:57

money's not here. Well, your money's

2:59

in Joe's house, on Mrs. Meiklin's house, and

3:01

100 others. It's just money. It's

3:03

made up. It doesn't exist. It's not real.

3:05

It's not a lie. If

3:07

you believe it. How

3:10

the hell do you put a price on a bat? Like,

3:13

I'm really curious. Well,

3:17

there's a couple of different things you can do. After

3:19

that conference, Amy wound up doing a whole research

3:22

paper on the value of bats. And

3:24

she started by thinking through the value of a

3:26

bat's labor. Not to put

3:28

a price on the bat, but

3:31

to put a price on its work. So

3:34

I'm thinking about Richard

3:36

Scarry books, and all the little

3:38

animals out there doing their jobs.

3:40

Squirrels planting the trees. Yes, yes.

3:44

And they all have jobs, and they're all wearing

3:46

their cute little outfits. And bats are out there

3:49

doing pest control. So

3:52

they are really helpful to farmers in

3:55

that they eat insects that are

3:57

pests to crops, the damaged crops.

4:00

Basically, bats are doing free labor

4:02

on farms all across America. But

4:05

Amy still had to figure out how to actually

4:07

put a price on that work. So

4:11

if you're not an economist and somebody says, oh

4:14

no, bats are dying, the inclination

4:16

is to say,

4:19

well, it's gonna wipe out

4:21

two-thirds of the crop and it's gonna

4:23

be really a huge impact. The

4:25

thing is, the people are

4:27

very adaptable. And

4:30

so if a service that nature

4:32

was providing goes away or is

4:34

reduced, we're not just

4:36

gonna sit around and do nothing. Farmers

4:39

are gonna say, well, okay, I've got

4:41

more pests, so I'm gonna

4:43

have to use more pesticide. So Amy

4:45

thought, okay, maybe one way to get

4:47

at the value of bats is to just

4:49

figure out how much it would cost to replace them.

4:52

But she couldn't know on every

4:55

single farm exactly what each

4:57

bat contributes. We can't

4:59

see them going around catching bugs

5:02

and we can't measure the bugs. We can't ask

5:04

the bats how many bugs they eat. It's

5:07

also not really practical to try and

5:09

call up every farmer and ask like,

5:11

what interventions have you used and how

5:13

much did they cost? What we

5:15

have to do is we have to say to ourselves, how

5:18

would this manifest

5:20

in things we can observe,

5:23

which is markets. And that's how Amy

5:25

chose to look at the price of land. Basically,

5:29

if you're a farmer and you're thinking about a piece

5:31

of land that you might rent or grow crops on,

5:34

you have to do a lot of math. You're gonna

5:36

think to yourself, well, how profitable is it

5:38

gonna be? What's the price of my inputs?

5:40

You know, what's the weather like these days? Farmer

5:43

stuff. Farmer stuff. How

5:45

much am I likely to have to spend on

5:48

pesticides? And all

5:50

of that goes into your calculation

5:53

of farmland profitability and

5:55

your demand for farmland. Bats

6:00

are doing free labor on the land.

6:02

They're eating up all these bugs. That

6:04

might make the land more valuable, like

6:06

more expensive to rent. On

6:08

the flip side, if the bats disappear,

6:11

you should then see the price of land go

6:13

down. Or at least that

6:15

was Amy's hypothesis. So she

6:17

and her colleagues pulled up a bunch of

6:19

maps. First, for example, they pulled

6:22

out the USDA data on how many acres

6:24

were farmed county by county across the U.S.

6:27

and also the average cropland

6:29

rental rates. This gave them a

6:31

sense of how the price of land changed over time.

6:34

But they also needed to know, what are the bats

6:36

up to? Which counties

6:38

had white-nose syndrome in

6:41

each year? This year, there

6:43

was no white-nose syndrome. When

6:46

you look later and you

6:48

see, okay, now this area

6:50

has white-nose syndrome, what impact

6:52

did that have on acres

6:54

planted and the price of land? Finally,

6:58

after a lot of data crunching, these

7:01

researchers had clear numbers showing how

7:03

white-nose syndrome had affected the price

7:05

of land across the U.S. We

7:08

found that losing bats in

7:10

a county caused land

7:13

rental rates to fall

7:15

by almost $3 an acre. And

7:18

there were also spillover effects. The

7:21

neighboring counties also experienced

7:23

some effects, which

7:25

makes sense because bats fly. Bats

7:27

fly. Yeah. When

7:29

Amy and her colleagues tallied everything up, they

7:31

came up with a pretty big price tag.

7:34

The bottom line is that

7:36

the cost to society of

7:38

white-nose syndrome in total was

7:41

between $420 and $500 million a year. Half

7:46

a billion dollars a year. The

7:50

best hope for stopping white-nose syndrome

7:52

is probably a vaccine or a

7:54

fungicide, but still years away. In

7:56

hard-hit Pennsylvania, those scientists are hoping

7:58

to slow the... fungus by

8:00

changing the temperature of bat caves.

8:02

Bat houses are being sprayed with

8:04

a naturally occurring bacteria that inhibits

8:06

the deadly fungus. Suddenly

8:09

spending $2 million to fight off

8:11

white nose syndrome or sending people

8:13

into guano-infested caves just doesn't seem

8:15

like such a big trade-off anymore.

8:17

White nose prevention on the way.

8:21

And eating bugs is just one example

8:23

of a way that bats are useful

8:25

to our economy. Like some might be

8:27

eating mosquitoes that carry diseases. Others

8:29

are, I don't know,

8:32

pooping, because poop is actually really

8:34

rich in nutrients and that's valuable

8:36

as a fertilizer. So here

8:38

we captured the value of one use

8:40

value, as

8:43

we call it. Use value, like literally

8:46

how useful bats are to our economy

8:48

in dollars. But there's

8:50

also this whole other way economists might

8:52

measure the value of animals or nature.

8:56

Some people, and I will include myself

8:58

here, value bats and

9:00

biodiversity in general for other reasons.

9:03

We see value in just having bats

9:05

around, whether or not we

9:07

actually benefit from them directly. Bats

9:09

are cool. Bats are cute. Bats

9:11

are really interesting. You know, you have summer

9:13

nights and you have them flying around up

9:16

above making their little clicky bat

9:18

noises. Amy says that economists

9:20

also try to measure this. They

9:22

try to figure out exactly how much

9:25

an animal or a plant or

9:27

like an ecosystem is worth to

9:29

us, spiritually and emotionally. Like

9:31

how much we value biodiversity, just for the

9:34

sake of having a rich and complex

9:36

world around us. And they

9:38

call this non-use value. And

9:40

we see people donating money

9:42

to save species that

9:45

they will never interact with on

9:47

an individual basis. It's not

9:49

affecting any market. It's

9:52

just out there. And

9:54

we might just want to save

9:56

it just because it is. And

9:59

while Amy hasn't measured... non-use values for

10:01

bats yet. She says that

10:03

researchers can actually put concrete numbers on

10:05

this too. It's just trickier. You

10:08

can't just look at market data. The

10:11

whole point of non-use values is that

10:13

they exist distinct and

10:15

not interacting with any markets.

10:18

So we use this

10:21

approach because we have to have a fancy

10:23

name for it called stated preference, which

10:26

is just a way of saying, yeah,

10:28

tell me what it's worth. Essentially,

10:33

they just ask a bunch of people, like,

10:35

what is a wetland worth to you or

10:37

an animal or this park? Except

10:40

not so directly. We

10:43

don't just merge up to people and say, what's this

10:45

whale worth to you? It's a nice whale you got

10:47

there, shame if anything happened to it. We

10:49

don't do that. Exactly,

10:51

yeah. But they do try to figure

10:53

out how much someone would be willing to pay to save

10:56

something. This is actually a technical

10:58

term. They're willingness to pay for nature.

11:04

Amy has done research on how much people

11:06

value grasslands, like how much

11:08

they're willing to pay to have grasslands

11:10

around. It's a way

11:12

to capture the value that

11:14

somebody has for a thing.

11:17

Economists also try to capture value by

11:19

looking at something that they call willingness

11:22

to accept. Like, I

11:24

live in a world with polar

11:26

bears and monarch butterflies. If

11:28

either of those species were to go extinct, what

11:31

amount of money would we have to give you to

11:34

compensate you for loss? And

11:36

you can imagine that that number is often much

11:38

higher. What you would have

11:41

to give people to compensate them for

11:43

its disappearance would be vast.

11:48

All these calculations that Amy is talking about,

11:51

like all the studies about use values and

11:53

non-use values and willingness to pay for nature

11:55

or to accept the loss of it, they

11:58

might sound kind of a fear. But

12:01

these kinds of studies aren't just

12:04

academics musing in obscure journals. Research

12:06

like this actually plays a very

12:08

important role in how we make

12:11

environmental policy, especially in

12:13

the U.S. After

12:16

the break, why it matters that we get it right,

12:19

and whether that's even possible. Reboot:

12:30

Your credit card with Apple Cart the only

12:32

credit card design for I found it gives

12:34

you up to three percent daily cash back

12:37

on every purchase. Bless! Applecart has no fees

12:39

not even hidden once. Apply for Apple Card

12:41

now in the wallet app on I phone

12:43

Applecart issued by Goldman Sachs Bank Usa Salt

12:46

Lake City branch subject to credit approval. Variable.

12:48

A Pr for Apple card. Range from nineteen point

12:50

Two four percent to twenty nine point

12:52

four nine percent based on credit worthiness

12:54

rates as of February first, twenty twenty

12:56

Four terms and more. At. Apple Cart. Dot

12:58

Com. I'm

13:06

Batman. One

13:08

reason that we have environmental economists doing the

13:10

work that Amy Ando does, measuring

13:12

the value of a ferret or a stretch

13:15

of desert, is because of a big policy

13:17

shift in the 1980s. Members

13:19

of the Congress, the

13:22

President of the United States. In

13:25

1981, Ronald Reagan stood in front

13:28

of Congress and gave a speech to wild

13:30

applause. Thank you very much. He

13:32

basically explained to the crowd that

13:34

he's cracking down on regulations and

13:37

regulatory agencies. And finally, just

13:39

yesterday, I signed an executive order

13:41

that for the first time, provides

13:43

for effective and coordinated management of

13:46

the regulatory process. That

13:48

executive order, and another one from Bill Clinton a

13:50

few years later, created so

13:52

that a lot of regulations passed in the

13:54

US have to go through a cost benefit

13:57

analysis. So now, if you

13:59

want to pass regulations, to protect some

14:01

grasslands, say, you often need to

14:03

do a study showing how the benefits compare to

14:05

the costs. And you can find

14:08

project after project measuring things like the

14:10

benefits that trees bring to a city

14:12

or the use and non-use values of

14:14

wetlands. And these numbers show up

14:16

in pretty big fights. The misery

14:18

in the Gulf of Mexico continues. Who'll pay for

14:20

the cleanup? Like after the Deepwater Horizon

14:23

oil spill in 2010, the

14:25

government asked scientists to try and figure

14:28

out how much people valued the natural

14:30

resources that BP's oil had destroyed. BP

14:33

will have to pay billions for the oil

14:35

spill in the Gulf. The

14:37

point is that studies that put dollar

14:39

values on the natural world, they're powerful

14:42

tools. They help hold

14:44

companies accountable. They give people more

14:46

of a reason to save bats

14:48

and other animals. They really

14:50

defend biodiversity's interest in the real

14:52

world. Unfortunately though,

14:55

they also have some real world

14:57

problems. Yeah, yeah, so let me

14:59

take a pause to think about it and try

15:01

to organize my thoughts a little bit. This

15:04

very thoughtful person is Nathan

15:06

Chan. He's an environmental economist like

15:08

Amy and he actually wrote a paper with her

15:10

about what can go wrong when you try to

15:12

put a number on nature. The

15:14

first problem they found is that when you

15:16

ask someone to tell you about how much

15:18

they value something, like how much

15:21

they're willing to pay for it, their answer

15:23

often depends on just how much money they

15:26

have. So if someone has $10 million, they

15:29

could hypothetically pay up to $10 million

15:32

for the thing that they care about. Whereas if I'm

15:34

less wealthy and I only have $10,000, then

15:37

my willingness to pay for the benefits that I

15:39

get are capped at $10,000. And

15:42

the problem is that if you're using

15:44

these techniques to decide where to build

15:46

something like a polluting power plant, you

15:48

might accidentally say, oh,

15:51

this rich neighborhood thinks their green

15:53

space is really valuable. And this

15:55

poor neighborhood thinks their green space

15:57

is actually less valuable. to

16:00

this analysis, so we should therefore build in

16:02

the poor neighborhood. It might be

16:04

better to call it willingness and ability to pay.

16:07

The other thing is that in the US,

16:09

race and class are really tightly linked to

16:11

one another. And so the same

16:13

study might conclude that we should build that power

16:16

plant in a black or brown neighborhood. And

16:19

Nathan says the value that people ascribe to

16:21

a green space or a park isn't

16:24

only about how rich they are, it's

16:26

also about how welcome they might feel there.

16:29

Let's say it was in Central Park and I was being

16:31

made to feel unsafe by going there, then

16:35

I might not go there as often and it

16:37

might look like I'm not valuing Central Park, but

16:40

what we're actually learning from people's decisions isn't

16:42

that they're not valuing it. It's actually being

16:44

caused by the constraints that they're being put

16:46

under or the kind of social environment that

16:48

they're in. And so

16:51

what that would mean is that we might

16:53

grossly underestimate the valuation of green spaces for

16:55

black folks in a scenario like that. He

16:58

says economists might measure the value of

17:00

a park or whatever by tallying up

17:02

how much time people spend in it.

17:05

But if black and brown people use that

17:07

park less because of racism, that

17:10

would again skew these kinds of assessments. And

17:13

then people haven't only critiqued these

17:15

sorts of economic assessments, they've

17:17

also questioned the fundamental premise

17:20

of environmental economics. One

17:22

of the things we point out on the paper is, you know, like sometimes

17:26

even thinking about the monetary value of

17:28

this might be distracting us from what

17:30

really matters. They basically asked

17:33

whether we should even be putting a dollar number

17:35

on nature in the first place. Like,

17:37

are there circumstances where that's just not

17:39

appropriate? One of the maybe

17:41

more clear cut examples, I think, is if

17:43

we're talking about lands that have

17:45

sacred or historical meanings to certain groups

17:47

of people, that might be

17:49

a place where, you know, if we work

17:52

really hard to say this is worth X

17:54

million dollars, that's kind of distracting from the

17:56

broader point that this has kind of deeper

17:58

heritage significance to people. Like

18:00

there are some things that we do

18:02

for spiritual or historical or even like

18:04

moral reasons. We don't say, hey,

18:06

you shouldn't murder people because we have calculated

18:08

the precise economic value that people bring to

18:10

society or the amount that someone would pay

18:13

to keep them on Earth. Like that's ridiculous.

18:15

We just know that murder is bad. And

18:18

similarly, maybe we should just say, hey, destroying

18:20

the environment is also bad and you really

18:22

should not need a dollar number to know

18:25

that. I think that's one definite

18:27

limitation and one place where we

18:29

as economists need to be a little humble

18:32

with what our estimates can do and what

18:34

types of questions they can and should be

18:36

answering in the policy sphere. Actually,

18:38

I started my career saying I would never do this

18:41

kind of research at all ever. I

18:43

wasn't going to do valuation. And

18:46

I've interacted especially with a lot of biologists

18:48

who feel like as soon

18:50

as we put dollar values on things, we're

18:53

distracting from the more important argument.

18:55

Of moral certitude. And this is

18:57

absolutely a thing we have to

19:00

do. Over

19:03

time, I think nature

19:07

just gets attacked and attacked and

19:09

attacked. For Amy, economics can

19:11

be a really strong defense

19:14

against those kinds of attacks. Some

19:16

people you can convince

19:18

with moral

19:20

stories and art

19:23

and photographs and experiences.

19:26

Other people need to see the dollar values. A

19:30

couple of years ago, I worked with a whole team

19:32

of ecologists and we wrote a paper estimating

19:36

the benefits to the world

19:39

of preventing the next pandemic by

19:42

doing things to protect forests

19:44

and protect species that

19:47

would make crossover of

19:49

something like COVID-19 from nature

19:51

into people less likely. The

19:54

paper found that if governments invested $22 billion

19:57

a year on stuff like protecting

19:59

tropical rain. forest and preventing

20:01

wildlife trafficking, they could potentially

20:03

bring the risk of another

20:05

pandemic like way down. And

20:08

yes, $22 billion sounds like a lot of

20:10

money, until you realize that

20:12

by some estimates the cost of the COVID

20:14

pandemic was $14 trillion in

20:16

the US alone. It's a huge

20:18

amount of money, and that speaks

20:20

to governments, and it helps convince

20:22

people to do something. This

20:25

paper has been cited hundreds of times.

20:28

It was, for example, in a report on

20:30

wildlife risks that was pulled together for Congress

20:32

last year. If people

20:34

like Amy and Nathan don't do this work,

20:37

then when important people like policymakers

20:39

weigh the costs and benefits of

20:41

a project, nature's value might

20:43

come up as zero. This

20:57

is the first episode in a whole

21:00

series we're doing on economic unexplainables. Next

21:03

week, we'll look at how much we can actually do to

21:06

control inflation. It's

21:08

like the Fed is treated like the Wizrovos

21:10

behind the curtain, that they're in charge of

21:12

the economy and they do all these things.

21:14

It's like, no, the Fed share is not

21:16

in charge of the economy. In

21:19

many ways, he's watching it roll along like

21:21

the rest of us. So that

21:23

is next episode, but this episode was

21:25

produced by me, Bird Pinkerton, and

21:28

reported by Benji and me together. It was

21:31

edited by the wonderful Marianne McKeown,

21:33

with help from Jorge Jast. Meredith

21:35

Hadnott has been spearheading the series.

21:37

Mandy Nguyen helped me pull this

21:39

episode together, as did Noam Hasenfeld

21:41

and Noam also did the music.

21:44

Christian Ayala did the mixing and the

21:46

sound design. Melissa Hirsch did our fact

21:49

checking. And we are grateful

21:51

always to Brian Resnick for

21:53

co-founding the show. I

21:55

also want to say a special extra thanks

21:57

to Nathan Chan and to Amy Ando, for

22:00

their generosity in responding to follow-up

22:02

emails. If

22:04

you have questions about this episode

22:06

or thoughts, please send them to

22:09

us. We are at unexplainable at

22:11

vox.com. You can support this

22:13

show and all of Vox's journalism by

22:16

joining our membership program today. Go

22:19

to vox.com/members to sign

22:21

up. Or you

22:23

can also support the show by leaving us

22:25

a nice rating or a review. It

22:28

means a lot. Unexplainable is part

22:30

of the Vox Media Podcast Network, and

22:33

we will be back next week.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features